DIGRESSION CONCERNING BANKS OF DEPOSIT,
PARTICULARLY CONCERNING THAT OF AMSTERDAM
The currency of a great state, such as France or England,
generally consists almost entirely of its own coin. Should this
currency, therefore, be at any time worn, clipt, or otherwise
degraded below its standard value, the state by a reformation of
its coin can effectually re-establish its currency. But the
currency of a small state, such as Genoa or Hamburg, can seldom
consist altogether in its own coin, but must be made up, in a
great measure, of the coins of all the neighbouring states with
which its inhabitants have a continual intercourse. Such a state,
therefore, by reforming its coin, will not always be able to
reform its currency. If foreign bills of exchange are paid in
this currency, the uncertain value of any sum, of what is in its
own nature so uncertain, must render the exchange always very
much against such a state, its currency being, in all foreign
states, necessarily valued even below what it is worth.
In order to remedy the inconvenience to which this
disadvantageous exchange must have subjected their merchants,
such small states, when they began to attend to the interest of
trade, have frequently enacted, that foreign bills of exchange of
a certain value should be paid not in common currency, but by an
order upon, or by a transfer in the books of a certain bank,
established upon the credit, and under the protection of the
state; this bank being always obliged to pay, in good and true
money, exactly according to the standard of the state. The banks
of Venice, Genoa, Amsterdam, Hamburg, and Nuremberg, seem to have
been all originally established with this view, though some of
them may have afterwards been made subservient to other purposes.
The money of such banks being better than the common currency of
the country, necessarily bore an agio, which was greater or
smaller according as the currency was supposed to be more or less
degraded below the standard of the state. The agio of the Bank of
Hamburg, for example, which is said to be commonly about fourteen
per cent is the supposed difference between the good standard
money of the state, and the clipt, worn, and diminished currency
poured into it from all the neighbouring states.
Before 1609 the great quantity of clipt and worn foreign
coin, which the extensive trade of Amsterdam brought from all
parts of Europe, reduced the value of its currency about nine per
cent below that of good money fresh from the mint. Such money no
sooner appeared than it was melted down or carried away, as it
always is in such circumstances. The merchants, with plenty of
currency, could not always find a sufficient quantity of good
money to pay their bills of exchange; and the value of those
bills, in spite of several regulations which were made to prevent
it, became in a great measure uncertain.
In order to remedy these inconveniences, a bank was
established in 1609 under the guarantee of the city. This bank
received both foreign coin, and the light and worn coin of the
country at its real intrinsic value in the good standard money of
the country, deducting only so much as was necessary for
defraying the expense of coinage, and the other necessary expense
of management. For the value which remained, after this small
deduction was made, it gave a credit in its books. This credit
was called bank money, which, as it represented money exactly
according to the standard of the mint, was always of the same
real value, and intrinsically worth more than current money. It
was at the same time enacted, that all bills drawn upon or
negotiated at Amsterdam of the value of six hundred guilders and
upwards should be paid in bank money, which at once took away all
uncertainty in the value of those bills. Every merchant, in
consequence of this regulation, was obliged to keep an account
with the bank in order to pay his foreign bills of exchange,
which necessarily occasioned a certain demand for bank money.
Bank money, over and above its intrinsic superiority to
currency, and the additional value which this demand necessarily
gives it, has likewise some other advantages. It is secure from
fire, robbery, and other accidents; the city of Amsterdam is
bound for it; it can be paid away by a simple transfer, without
the trouble of counting, or the risk of transporting it from one
place to another. In consequence of those different advantages,
it seems from the beginning to have borne agio, and it is
generally believed that all the money originally deposited in the
bank was allowed to remain there, nobody caring to demand payment
of a debt which he could sell for a premium in the market. By
demanding payment of the bank, the owner of a bank credit would
lose this premium. As a shilling fresh from the mint will buy no
more goods in the market than one of our common worn shillings,
so the good and true money which might be brought from the
coffers of the bank into those of a private person, being mixed
and confounded with the common currency of the country, would be
of no more value than that currency from which it could no longer
be readily distinguished. While it remained in the coffers of the
bank, its superiority was known and ascertained. When it had come
into those of a private person, its superiority could not well be
ascertained without more trouble than perhaps the difference was
worth. By being brought from the coffers of the bank, besides, it
lost all the other advantages of bank money; its security, its
easy and safe transferability, its use in paying foreign bills of
exchange. Over and above all this, it could not be brought from
those coffers, as it will appear by and by, without previously
paying for the keeping.
Those deposits of coin, or those deposits which the bank was
bound to restore in coin, constituted the original capital of the
bank, or the whole value of what was represented by what is
called bank money. At present they are supposed to constitute but
a very small part of it. In order to facilitate the trade in
bullion, the bank has been for these many years in the practice
of giving credit in its books upon deposits of gold and silver
bullion. This credit is generally about five per cent below the
mint price of such bullion. The bank grants at the same time what
is called a recipe or receipt, entitling the person who makes the
deposit, or the bearer, to take out the bullion again at any time
within six months, upon re-transferring to the bank a quantity of
bank money equal to that for which credit had been given in its
books when the deposit was made, and upon paying one-fourth per
cent for the keeping, if the deposit was in silver; and one-half
per cent if it was in gold; but at the same time declaring that,
in default of such payment, and upon the expiration of this term,
the deposit should belong to the bank at the price at which it
had been received, or for which credit had been given in the
transfer books. What is thus paid for the keeping of the deposit
may be considered as a sort of warehouse rent; and why this
warehouse rent should be so much dearer for gold than for silver,
several different reasons have been assigned. The fineness of
gold, it has been said, is more difficult to be ascertained than
that of silver. Frauds are more easily practised, and occasion a
greater loss in the more precious metal. Silver, besides, being
the standard metal, the state, it has been said, wishes to
encourage more the making of deposits of silver than those of
gold.
Deposits of bullion are most commonly made when the price is
somewhat lower than ordinary; and they are taken out again when
it happens to rise. In Holland the market price of bullion is
generally above the mint price, for the same reason that it was
so in England before the late reformation of the gold coin. The
difference is said to be commonly from about six to sixteen
stivers upon the mark, or eight ounces of silver of eleven parts
fine and one part alloy. The bank price, or the credit which the
bank gives for deposits of such silver (when made in foreign
coin, of which the fineness is well known and ascertained, such
as Mexico dollars), is twenty-two guilders the mark; the mint
price is about twenty-three guilders, and the market price is
from twenty-three guilders six to twenty-three guilders sixteen
stivers, or from two to three per cent above the mint price.
1The proportions between the bank price, the mint price, and the
market price of gold bullion are nearly the same. A person can
generally sell his receipt for the difference between the mint
price of bullion and the market price. A receipt for bullion is
almost always worth something, and it very seldom happens,
therefore, that anybody suffers his receipt to expire, or allows
his bullion to fall to the bank at the price at which it had been
received, either by not taking it out before the end of the six
months, or by neglecting to pay the one-fourth or one-half per
cent in order to obtain a new receipt for another six months.
This, however, though it happens seldom, is said to happen
sometimes, and more frequently with regard to gold than with
regard to silver, on account of the higher warehouse-rent which
is paid for the keeping of the more precious metal.
Bar or ingot gold is received in proportion to its fineness
compared with the above foreign gold coin. Upon fine bars the
bank gives 340 per mark. In general, however, something more is
given upon coin of a known fineness, than upon gold and silver
bars, of which the fineness cannot be ascertained but by a
process of melting and assaying.
The person who by making a deposit of bullion obtains both a
bank credit and receipt, pays his bills of exchange as they
become due with his bank credit; and either sells or keeps his
receipt according as he judges that the price of bullion is
likely to rise or to fall. The receipt and the bank credit seldom
keep long together, and there is no occasion that they should.
The person who has a receipt, and who wants to take out bullion,
finds always plenty of bank credits, or bank money to buy at the
ordinary price; and the person who has bank money, and wants to
take out bullion, finds receipts always in equal abundance.
The owners of bank credits, and the holders of receipts,
constitute two different sorts of creditors against the bank. The
holder of a receipt cannot draw out the bullion for which it is
granted, without reassigning to the bank a sum of bank money
equal to the price at which the bullion had been received. If he
has no bank money of his own, he must purchase it of those who
have it. The owner of bank money cannot draw out bullion without
producing to the bank receipts for the quantity which he wants.
If he has none of his own, he must buy them of those who have
them. The holder of a receipt, when he purchases bank money,
purchases the power of taking out a quantity of bullion, of which
the mint price is five per cent above the bank price. The agio of
five per cent therefore, which he commonly pays for it, is paid
not for an imaginary but for a real value. The owner of bank
money, when he purchases a receipt, purchases the power of taking
out a quantity of bullion of which the market price is commonly
from two to three per cent above the mint price. The price which
he pays for it, therefore, is paid likewise for a real value. The
price of the receipt, and the price of the bank money, compound
or make up between them the full value or price of the bullion.
Upon deposits of the coin current in the country, the bank
grants receipts likewise as well as bank credits; but those
receipts are frequently of no value, and will bring no price in
the market. Upon ducatoons, for example, which in the currency
pass for three guilders three stivers each, the bank gives a
credit of three guilders only, or five per cent below their
current value. It grants a receipt likewise entitling the bearer
to take out the number of ducatoons deposited at any time within
six months, upon paying one-fourth per cent for the keeping. This
receipt will frequently bring no price in the market. Three
guilders bank money generally sell in the market for three
guilders three stivers, the full value of the ducatoons, if they
were taken out of the bank; and before they can be taken out,
one-fourth per cent must be paid for the keeping, which would be
mere loss to the holder of the receipt. If the agio of the bank,
however, should at any time fall to three per cent such receipts
might bring some price in the market, and might sell for one and
three-fourths per cent. But the agio of the bank being now
generally about five per cent such receipts are frequently
allowed to expire, or as they express it, to fall to the bank.
The receipts which are given for deposits of gold ducats fall to
it yet more frequently, because a higher warehouse-rent, or
one-half per cent must be paid for the keeping of them before
they can be taken out again. The five per cent which the bank
gains, when deposits either of coin or bullion are allowed to
fall to it, may be considered as the warehouse-rent for the
perpetual keeping of such deposits.
The sum of bank money for which the receipts are expired
must be very considerable. It must comprehend the whole original
capital of the bank, which, it is generally supposed, has been
allowed to remain there from the time it was first deposited,
nobody caring either to renew his receipt or to take out his
deposit, as, for the reasons already assigned, neither the one
nor the other could be done without loss. But whatever may be the
amount of this sum, the proportion which it bears to the whole
mass of bank money is supposed to be very small. The Bank of
Amsterdam has for these many years past been the great warehouse
of Europe for bullion, for which the receipts are very seldom
allowed to expire, or, as they express it, to fall to the bank.
far greater part of the bank money, or of the credits upon the
books of the bank, is supposed to have been created, for these
many years past, by such deposits which the dealers in bullion
are continually both making and withdrawing.
No demand can be made upon the bank but by means of a recipe
or receipt. The smaller mass of bank money, for which the
receipts are expired, is mixed and confounded with the much
greater mass for which they are still in force; so that, though
there may be a considerable sum of bank money for which there are
no receipts, there is no specific sum or portion of it which may
not at any time be demanded by one. The bank cannot be debtor to
two persons for the same thing; and the owner of bank money who
has no receipt cannot demand payment of the bank till he buys
one. In ordinary and quiet times, he can find no difficulty in
getting one to buy at the market price, which generally
corresponds with the price at which he can sell the coin or
bullion it entities him to take out of the bank.
It might be otherwise during a public calamity; an invasion,
for example, such as that of the French in 1672. The owners of
bank money being then all eager to draw it out of the bank, in
order to have it their own keeping, the demand for receipts might
raise their price to an exorbitant height. The holders of them
might form expectations, and, instead of two or three per cent,
demand half the bank money for which credit had been given upon
the deposits that the receipts had respectively been granted for.
The enemy, informed of the constitution of the bank, might even
buy them up, in order to prevent the carrying away of the
treasure. In such emergencies, the bank, it is supposed, would
break through its ordinary rule of making payment only to the
holders of receipts. The holders of receipts, who had no bank
money, must have received within two or three per cent of the
value of the deposit for which their respective receipts had been
granted. The bank, therefore, it is said, would in this case make
no scruple of paying, either with money or bullion, the full
value of what the owners of bank money who could get no receipts
were credited for in its books; paying at the same time two or
three per cent to such holders of receipts as had no bank money,
that being the whole value which in this state of things could
justly be supposed due to them.
Even in ordinary and quiet times it is the interest of the
holders of receipts to depress the agio, in order either to buy
bank money (and consequently the bullion, which their receipts
would then enable them to take out of the bank) so much cheaper,
or to sell their receipts to those who have bank money, and who
want to take out bullion, so much dearer; the price of a receipt
being generally equal to the difference between the market price
of bank money, and that of the coin or bullion for which the
receipt had been granted. It is the interest of the owners of
bank money, on the contrary, to raise the agio, in order either
to sell their bank money so much dearer, or to buy a receipt so
much cheaper. To prevent the stock-jobbing tricks which those
opposite interests might sometimes occasion, the bank has of late
years come to the resolution to sell at all times bank money for
currency, at five per cent agio, and to buy it in again at four
per cent agio. In consequence of this resolution, the agio can
never either rise above five or sink below four per cent, and the
proportion between the market price of bank and that of current
money is kept at all times very near to the proportion between
their intrinsic values. Before this resolution was taken, the
market price of bank money used sometimes to rise so high as nine
per cent agio, and sometimes to sink so low as par, according as
opposite interests happened to influence the market.
The Bank of Amsterdam professes to lend out no part of what
is deposited with it, but, for every guilder for which it gives
credit in its books, to keep in its repositories the value of a
guilder either in money or bullion. That it keeps in its
repositories all the money or bullion for which there are
receipts in force, for which it is at all times liable to be
called upon, and which, in reality, is continually going from it
and returning to it again, cannot well be doubted. But whether it
does so likewise with regard to that part of its capital, for
which the receipts are long ago expired, for which in ordinary
and quiet times it cannot be called upon, and which in reality is
very likely to remain with it for ever, or as long as the States
of the United Provinces subsist, may perhaps appear more
uncertain. At Amsterdam, however, no point of faith is better
established than that for every guilder, circulated as bank
money, there is a correspondent guilder in gold or silver to be
found in the treasure of the bank. The city is guarantee that it
should be so. The bank is under the direction of the four
reigning burgomasters who are changed every year. Each new set of
burgomasters visits the treasure, compares it with the books,
receives it upon oath, and delivers it over, with the same awful
solemnity, to the set which succeeds; and in that sober and
religious country oaths are not yet disregarded. A rotation of
this kind seems alone a sufficient security against any practices
which cannot be avowed. Amidst all the revolutions which faction
has ever occasioned in the government of Amsterdam, the
prevailing party has at no time accused their predecessors of
infidelity in the administration of the bank. No accusation could
have affected more deeply the reputation and fortune of the
disgraced party, and if such an accusation could have been
supported, we may be assured that it would have been brought. In
1672, when the French king was at Utrecht, the Bank of Amsterdam
paid so readily as left no doubt of the fidelity with which it
had observed its engagements. Some of the pieces which were then
brought from its repositories appeared to have been scorched with
the fire which happened in the town-house soon after the bank was
established. Those pieces, therefore, must have lain there from
that time.
What may be the amount of the treasure in the bank is a
question which has long employed speculations of the curious.
Nothing but conjecture can be offered concerning it. It is
generally reckoned that there are about two thousand people who
keep accounts with the bank, and allowing them to have, one with
another, the value of fifteen hundred pounds sterling lying upon
their respective accounts (a very large allowance), the whole
quantity of bank money, and consequently of treasure in the bank,
will amount to about three millions sterling, or, at eleven
guilders the pound sterling, thirty-three millions of guilders- a
great sum, and sufficient to carry on a very extensive
circulation, but vastly below the extravagant ideas which some
people have formed of this treasure.
The city of Amsterdam derives a considerable revenue from
the bank. Besides what may be called the warehouse-rent above
mentioned, each person, upon first opening an account with the
bank, pays a fee of ten guilders; and for every new account three
guilders three stivers; for every transfer two stivers; and if
the transfer is for less than three hundred guilders, six
stivers, in order to discourage the multiplicity of small
transactions. The person who neglects to balance his account
twice in the year forfeits twenty-five guilders. The person who
orders a transfer for more than is upon his account, is obliged
to pay three per cent for the sum overdrawn, and his order is set
aside into the bargain. The bank is supposed, too, to make a
considerable profit by the sale of the foreign coin or bullion
which sometimes falls to it by the expiring of receipts, and
which is always kept till it can be sold with advantage. It makes
a profit likewise by selling bank money at five per cent agio,
and buying it in at four. These different emoluments amount to a
good deal more than what is necessary for paying the salaries of
officers, and defraying the expense of management. What is paid
for the keeping of bullion upon receipts is alone supposed to
amount to a neat annual revenue of between one hundred and fifty
thousand and two hundred thousand guilders. Public utility,
however, and not revenue, was the original object of this
institution. Its object was to relieve the merchants from the
inconvenience of a disadvantageous exchange. The revenue which
has arisen from it was unforeseen, and may be considered as
accidental. But it is now time to return from this long
digression, into which I have been insensibly led in endeavouring
to explain the reasons why the exchange between the countries
which pay in what is called bank money, and those which pay in
common currency, should generally appear to be in favour of the
former and against the latter. The former pay in a species of
money of which the intrinsic value is always the same, and
exactly agreeable to the standard of their respective mints; the
latter is a species of money of which the intrinsic value is
continually varying, and is almost always more or less below that
standard.
[1.]
The following are the prices at which the Bank of Amsterdam at
present (September, 1775) receives bullion and coin of different
kind:-
SILVER
- Mexico dollars: Guilders B-22 per mark
- French crowns: Guilders B-22 per mark
- English silver coin: Guilders B-22 per mark
- Mexico dollars new coin: 21 10
- Ducatoons: 3
- Rix dollars: 2 8
- Bar silver containing eleven-twelfths fine silver 21 per
mark, and in this proportion down to 1/4 fine, on which 5
guilders are given.
- Fine bars, 93 per mark.
GOLD
- Portugal coin: B-310 per mark
- Guineas: B-310 per mark
- Louis d'ors new: B-310 per mark
- Ditto old: 300
- New ducats: 4 19 8 per ducat
- Bar ingot gold is received in proportion to its fitness compared
with the above foreign gold coin. Upon fine bars the bank gives 340 per
mark. In general, however, something more is given upon coin of a known
fineness than upon gold and silver bars, of which the fineness cannot be
ascertained but by a process of melting and assaying. (Note by the
author.)